Suppose you and I are the only two individuals in the world and we both face individual risk in the following way: I get more consumption in state 1 than in state 2 while you get more consumption in state 2 than in state 1.

a. Suppose we are both risk averse and our tastes are state-independent. Will we fully insure one another in a competitive equilibrium?

b. How does your answer change if there is aggregate risk in the sense that overall consumption is higher in state 2 than in state 1?
c. Is it possible that we insure each other if our tastes are risk neutral and state-independent? If so, are the terms actuarily fair?
d. Suppose that there is no aggregate risk but our tastes are state-dependent. How might we fully insure each other if our beliefs about the probability of each state differ?

What will be an ideal response?


a. Yes. (See panel (a) of Graph 17.10 in the text.)


b. We can no longer fully insure each other. (See Graph 17.11 in the text.)


c. Risk neutrality implies that our indifference curves are straight lines. This implies they cannot be tangent in the Edgeworth Box -- unless they lie right on top of one another. But this is precisely the case as our indifference curves have the same slope (given state-independence) as long as we have common beliefs about probabilities. That slope is the same as the slope of the contract line that incorporates actuarily fair terms of trade. Thus, any insurance will be actuarily fair -- although none of it will make either party better (or worse) off.


d. State-dependence of tastes will cause individuals to no longer want to fully insure when terms are actuarily fair (as they would under state-independent tastes and no aggregate risk). This is because the slopes if indifference curves along the 45-degree line no are no longer equal to actuarily fair slopes of contract lines. But if beliefs differ, the slopes of our indifference curves might still be equal along the 45 degree line -- making it possible that we might fully insure each other.

Economics

You might also like to view...

The hands-off view of the classical school rests on which of the following two simple propositions about markets?

a. Demand creates its own supply and markets are basically competitive. b. Industrial policy is inevitable and all prices are flexible. c. Market failure occurs and prices are rigid. d. Wages are sticky downward and market failure is inevitable. e. Markets are basically competitive and prices are flexible.

Economics

Which of the following is not a characteristic of most less-developed countries?

a. low per capita income b. political instability c. a high percentage of the population under the age of 15 d. inadequate infrastructure e. high productivity

Economics

Which of the following is an example of discrimination in the labor market?

a. Women earn less than men because women are more likely to be employed in occupations that pay less, such as elementary school teachers rather than electrical engineers. b. Women earn less than men because women have, on average, fewer years of experience in the labor force because women, on average, periodically leave the labor force to raise children. c. A pharmaceutical sales company pays women less than men because the company's customers, physicians and pharmacists, say that they prefer to deal with men rather than women. d. All of the above are examples of discrimination.

Economics

Economic growth due to labor force expansion or capital investments will result in

I. A leftward shift of short-run aggregate supply. II. A rightward shift in long-run aggregate supply. A) I only B) II only C) Both I and II D) Neither I nor II

Economics